Saturday, 3 January 2015

29.(MEDIEVAL INDIA) SOCIETY- STRUCTURE AND GROWTH

References: Satish Chandra(Medieval India).Also minor facts from other books and figure and facts from verified Internet sources.
                       29. SOCIETY- STRUCTURE AND GROWTH



The social structure during the Sultanat period, which we have analyzed earlier, continued to operate


under Mughal rule, showing signs of both continuity and change. The most important changes were the


further strafication of rural society; growth of urbanization and of the class of artisans and master artisans, the growth of a composite ruling class accompanied with bureaucratization and


commercialization; the growth of middle segments, and the further expansion and strengthening of the


commercial classes. While it is difficult to form a precise idea of the total population of the country in


the absence of statistics, by utilizing the statistics of the cultivated area, yields, revenue rates and the


jama or the estimated revenue demand from land, modern scholors have put the population of the


country at the end of the 16th century between 140 and 150 million which slowly increased to 200


million by the end of the 18th century, thus giving a population growth rate of 0.14 per cent per annum.


Rural Society


During the 16th and 17th centuries, about 85 per cent of India's population lived in rural areas. Any


study of the social system should, therefore, start with the villages. However, in contemporary historical


sources, including the accounts of the large number of foreign travellers who visited India during the


period, we have hardly any account of life in the rural areas. The deficiency has been made up to some


extent by the large mass of documents dealing with land revenue and rural affairs pertaining to the


various states of Rajasthan, Marathi records of the 18th century, and Mughal documents mainly dealing


with the Deccan. Literary sources, too, provide some information on rural life and conditions.


359


A main feature of rural society in the country, excluding tribal areas, was its highly stratified nature.


People were divided and grouped on the basis of their resident status, caste, and position as office


holders. While there were considerable differences in their material status, material situation was not a


primary factor in fixing their position in rural society.


Resident Cultivators: Riyayatis and Khud Kasht


The largest section in the village consisted of cultivators, the large majority of whom claimed to be


descendants of original settlers of the village. The word used in Sanskrit for old settlers was sthanik or


resident, and the words thani or stalwahak for such settlers in Maharashtra were obviously derived from


it. Other words, such as mirasi in Maharashtra, or gaonveti or gaveti in Rajasthan were also in use for


these sections.


The resident cultivators were often divided into two: the riyayati and the raiyati, or the privileged and


the ordinary. The riyayati section consisted of the resident owner-cultivators, for whom the word mirasi


was used in Maharashtra, and gharu-hala in parts of Rajasthan. The word used in Persian was khud


kasht. According to a late 18th century glossary, the word khud kasht is defined as one who, "having


paid himself the money (for the purchase of) oxen etc, gets the cultivation done by the peasants


(riaya)". It sums up by saying, "if the owner of land (malik-i-zamin) cultivates his own land, he is called


khud-kasht"


Thus, resident status in the village, ownership of land, and cultivating the land with the help of family


labour, supplemented by hired labour, were the characteristic features of the khud-kasht. The khudkasht not only paid land revenue at a concessional rate, but were exempt, partially or wholly, from


various imposts, such as tax on marriages. Nor did a khud-kasht pay any house tax as long as he had only


one habitation in the village. But as a perceptive British administrator of the 18th century W.W. Hunter,


observed:


360


"The khud-kasht right was a valuable right, not only because it implied an economic advantage, but


because it conferred a certain social status. The resident cultivators formed the governing body of the


village community its bhadralok or respectable class." They had a number of other privileges, such as


access to village pastures and forest lands, to the water reservoir and the fishes, and to the services of


the village servants or officials.


Apart from the khud-kasht, the privileged section or riyayatis comprised in Rajasthan and perhaps in


many parts of the country, of those belonging to the higher castes, Brahman, Rajput and Mahajan


(bania), as also the local village officials, such as the patel or chaudhari, quanungo, patwari, etc. though


many of these may have been drawn from the body of the khud-kasht.


The riyayatis had a separate dastur or tax regulation in various parts of the country. In Rajasthan,


according to documents, these sections paid one-fourth of the produce, whereas the normal demand


was from one-fourth to half. It should be noted however, that due to caste taboo, brahmans did not


cultivate the land themselves, but had it ploughed through hired labour. Also, as we shall see,


concessions in land-revenue was given on occasions to other sections also.


Pahis or Outsiders


The khud-kasht or owner-cultivators are sometimes equated wrongly with the entire body of resident


cultivators. They are also contrasted with the pahi or pai-kasht who came from neighbouring villages or


parganas to cultivate surplus land, or to resettle a ruined village or to settle a new one. In many cases,


the pahis were given pattas at concessional rates, the full rate being paid in the third or fifth year, or


even later. Thus, we are told that village Mehrajpur in pargana Malarna (Eastern Rajasthan) which had


been deserted in 1728 on account of failure of rains and the wells and ponds having dried up, was


resettled when the former patel was asked to settle in the village and give an undertaking that he would


bring the entire land of the village under plough. He was given a patta at the rate of one-third of the


produce for three years. The pahi-kasht who came to the village were given pattas for paying one-third


of the produce for the current year.


Such concession could vary, both in terms of amount and duration, depending on circumstances. When


the pahis had no implements of their own, they were provided with ploughs, bullocks, seeds, manure


and money either directly by the state, or by the village money-lender (bohra). They were also allowed


to retain their fields as long as they continued to pay land-revenue.


The movement of peasants from village to village, either due to natural factors, such as famins, or manmade factors, such as war or local oppresion was not a new feature. It is referred to by


361


the Hindi poet, Tulsidas, in the 16th century. It was an old feature that peasants moved from their


villages to improve their conditions, such as settling a new village, or expanding cultivation in an old


village or resettling it. Thus, rural society' was not as fixed and unchanging as we often picture it; though


the structure itself hardly underwent any change. Thus, a new village was settled on the same structure


as the old one. During periods of unrest, the number of pahis must have increased, as is the evidence for


the 18th century. But we do not have any documents for the earlier period to make a comparion.


Sometimes the pahis were drawn from the section of dalits who came to new or ruined villages in the


hope of acquiring ownership rights over the lands they had brought under the plough. Such a


development was generally not possible in their own villages due to social taboos. But we do find


instances in many areas, such as Kota, where peasants from the dalit sections were allowed to become


owners of land.


It would not be correct to treat pahis as temporary or migrating workers because most of them settled


in the village and could, in course of time which could extend to one or more generation, be absorbed in


the body of resident cultivators.


The Raiyatis


The general category of cultivators were called raiyatis or paltis in Rajasthan. The Persian word used for


them was muzarian. The paltis generally belonged to middle castes - Jat, Gujar, Mali, Ahir, Meena etc.


They could be either owners (malik, dhani) of the lands they cultivated, or tenants. The raiyati owner


cultivators were assessed according to the raiyati dastur which itself was variable, according to the


nature of the crop, the season, means of irrigation etc. However, as a norm, the land revenue levied on


polaj land on the ordinary peasant was normally one-half of the produce. Wheat and bajra was charged


at two-fifth. Land-revenue did not include other cesses (jihat).


Raiyati or palti tenants have been divided into two — state tenants who cultivated the cultivatable


wasteland (banjar), or cultivated the land abandoned by a dhani or an owner-cultivator. Such tenants


usually had their own ploughs and oxen, and were given a patta which could be for one year, or a single


harvest. The patta was generallay renewable. The second category of tenants were dhani tenants who


tilled the personal lands of zamindars,


362


bhomias, patels, holders of inam lands etc. Very often they were dependent on the mahajan, zamindar


and the patel for bullocks, ploughs, seeds, etc. They either paid rent in addition to the land-revenue to


the owner of the land or cultivated it on the basis of share-cropping. These cultivators had low social


esteem, and sometimes the word palti applied to them was used in a derogatory sense. The paltis also


moved from village to village for better terms, or were offered concessional terms for settling a


deserted or a new village. These paltis are sometimes indistinguishable from pahis.


Apart from the cultivators, there were landless persons who worked as labourers (majurs). In addition,


there were the service people - the ironsmith, the carpenter, the rope-maker, the potter, the leather


worker, barber, washermen, the village watchman, etc. In Maharashtra, these service sectors were


twelve in number who were called balutedars, receiving a prescribed share (baluta) from the village


produce. There was another sections called alutedars, which were "neither essential nor universal in the


Deccan villages, only some of them were occassionally found in the larger villages". They were the


village priests, tailor, water carrier, gardner, drum-beater, volcalist, musician, oil presser, betel nut


seller, gold smith etc. These received a lower share of the produce or were given a strip of land for their


remuneration. The landless and the bulk of the service classes were designated kamin or low, and


included a sizable section of dalits.


It is difficult to estimate the proportion of the three principal sections - the riyayati, the raiyati, and the


service classes. In some estimates pertaining to eastern Rajasthan, the riyayati or privileged classes


amounted to 13 percent; the service classes 11 percent and the remainder 76 percent. Even this does


not give a true picture of the gross inequalities in village society. According to a takhmina document


about mauza Chandawar in Eastern Rajasthan in 1666, out of 86 cultivators, 9 cultivated on an average


about 126 bighas each, 23 cultivators had 70 bighas of land each under actual cultivation, and the


remaining 50 cultivated 30 bighas of land each. A study of two villages in pargana Chatsu in V.S. 1723/


A.D. 1666 shows that while in Chatsu village, only 10 asamis (5 percent of the total) had 5 to 8 oxen


each, 61 asamis (30.5 percent) had one oxen each which was insufficient for cultivation. The remaining


129 asamis (64 percent) had 2 to 4 oxen. In another village, Kotkhwada, the proportion was 8.8 percent


of the asamis


363


with 5 to 7 oxen, 21.5 percent with one ox, and 69.2 percent with 2 to 4. This picture is repeated in the


case of ploughs. Thus, in village Multhan 4 asamis (10 percent) had 3 to 5 ploughs, while the rest had


one to two ploughs.


From this limited evidence, we may not be for wrong in concluding that while the large majority of the


cultivators belonged to the middling status, in many of the bigger villages, there were 4 to 15 asamis,


constituting 5 to 10 percent of the total, who were financially affluent. At the other end of the spectrum,


there were 15 to 30 percent cultivators in many villages who did not have land or means of cultivation,


and who could be classified poor. This does not include the landless and the poorer sections in the


service classes.


We do not have sufficient information at present to decide whether poverty was growing, or the rich


becoming richer. A general assumption is that whenever the control of the government, whether central


or local, weakened, the richer sections in the villages transferred their burden on to the shoulders of the


weaker sections. However, the main point to note is that rural society in Mughal India was not an


undifferentiated mass of pauperized peasants.


The question is, what effect did this disparity have on the growth pattern of the village? We have


evidence of both negative and positive aspects. Negatively, the richer sections including the mahajans,


lent oxen, ploughs, seeds, etc. to the weaker sections for cultivation, or lent money for payment of land revenue and realized their dues with interest at the time of harvest. They foreclosed the land in case of


default. Similarly, in times of famine, the richer sections of the village lent money to the weaker


sections, and used their resources to bring under their cultivation abandoned fields. The state hardly


interfered, its main concern being to ensure that raiyati lands were not converted by the privileged


sections into riyayati lands which paid land-revenue at a concessional rate.


At the positive level, it is the privileged sections, including the village zamindar, and the rich cultivators


who played a leading role in providing money, implements and organization for expanding and


improving cultivation, including introduction of higher quality crops, such as wh eat and cash-crops


(cotton, indigo, oil-seeds etc.) which meant additional investment, and


364


new crops (such as tobacco, maize etc.). The superior crops needed more water, and were generally


more labour intensive.


Thus, the processes of stratification and growth of income disparity, and of expansion and improvement


of cultivation went on side by side. But these could be disrupted in case of a general breakdown of law


and order or absence of an equitable approach towards levying and collection of land-revenue.


Village Community


Although the word "village community" was popularized by British administrators, such as Baden-Powel,


and picked up by nationalist leaders as a basis for Indian democracy, there is no equivalent for the word


in Indian languages. The reason for this was that the "village" itself implified a local community,


howsover divided by caste, office, economic status etc. As we have seen, the village panchayat was


dominated by the resident cultivators, or a few persons drawn from that section. We have also seen


that land was not held by the village community, but by individuals who were assessed separately.


However, the body of resident cultivators were sometimes held responsible for the payment of the


assessed land - revenue. This was a devise to prevent the flight of peasants from the village as far as


possible. As the zamindars became stronger during the eighteenth century, following the growing


weakness of centralized government, the role of the resident cultivators in regulating the internal affairs


of the village also became weaker.


Towns and Town Life


Towns and town-life are considered to be an index of the state of development and culture in a country.


According to Abdul Fazl, "People that are attached to the world will collect in towns, without which


there would be no progress." City life was a special feature of Muslim civilization. A noted French


historian of modern times, Fernand Braudel says, "Towns are like electric transformers. They increase


tension, accelerate the rythm of exchange and constantly recharge human life. Towns generate


expansion and are themselves generated by it." (Civilization and Capitalism: 15th - 18th Century).


We had noted in an earlier volume the growth of towns and town-life in India during the Sultanat


period. The process of the


365


growth of towns became faster during the 16th and 17th centuries, and continued till the middle of the


18th century.


There is no agreement among scholars regarding the size of a town, though it is generally agreed that


the size of a town depends on the population of a country. The basic feature of a town is the existence


of a market. The smallest towns in India, the qasba, has been defined as a village with a market, in other


words, it had the characteristics of village life, viz. agricultural production, and a market. Generally


speaking, a qasba was also a pargana headquarter. There was a hirearchy of towns from the humble


qasba to the district (sarkar) headquarter where the faujdar resided, to the provincial and imperial


towns like Agra, Delhi, Lahore, etc.


We are told that in Akbar's empire, there were 120 big cities and 3200 townships or rural towns


(qasbas). These did not include the towns and townships in South India. In the 17th century, the largest


city was Agra with an estimated population of 500,000 which rose to 600,000 when the Emperor was in


the town. It still remained very large when the court shifted back to Delhi in the middle of the 17th


Century. Delhi was now held to be as populous as Paris which was then the biggest town in Europe.


According to a traveller,Coryat, in the beginning of the 17th century, Lahore was bigger than Agra, and


was "one of the largest cities of the whole universe". Ahmadabad was estimated to be larger than


London and its subarbs. Patna, we are told, had a population of 200,000. Other large towns included


Dacca, Rajmahal, Thatta, Burhanpur, Masulipatam.


However, what mattered was not so much the size as the nature of the towns and the role they played


in the social, economic and cultural life of the country. According to a recent estimate, during the 17th


Century there was a very high ratio of urban to the total population of the country, as much as 15 per


cent, a proportion which was not exceeded till the middle of the 20th century. Even if this figure of


urbanization may be disputed, it is agreed that in Mughal India, the largest towns were "thriving centres


of manufacuring and marketing, banking and enterpreneurial activities, intersections in a network of


communications by land and water which crossed and re-crossed the sub-continent and extended far


beyond, to South East Asia, to the Middle East, to Western Europe, and elsewhere." (Gavin Hambly in


Cambridge Economic History of India, Vol.1).


366


Four distinct types of urban centres can be identified. First, there were cities whose prime function was


administrative where other roles, such as manufacturing or religion were of secondary importance.


These were cities such as Agra, Delhi, Lahore, as well as many provincial capitals., Later, Poona,


Faizabad, Haiderabad emerged as important centres of this type. Secondly, there were cities which had


a predominantly commercial and manufacturing character to which may be attached some


administrative functions. Cities such as Patna, and Ahmadabad fell in this category. Thirdly, there were


the piligrim centres where some trade and craft activities also flourished, but which had a large floating


population. Cities such as Banaras and Mathura, Kanci and Tirumalai in South India fall in this category.


Ajmer was both religious and administrative in character. Lastly, there were centres which flourished


because of distinctive manufacturing technique or skill or local commodity. Bayana because of indigo,


Patan in Gujarat for dyeing, Khairabad in Awadh for textiles fell in this category.


On account of the peace and law and order established by the Mughals in north and central India, and


the consequent growth of commerce and manufacture, the period has been conceived of a "veritable


golden age of urbanization". Of course, the process was not the same in different parts of the empire -Western U.P. and Eastern Punjab were the most rapidly developing till the end of the 17th century,


while eastern U.P. and Bihar and Bengal forged ahead in the first half of the 18th century, due to the


strong rule of the Nawabs or local rulers. Poona, Hugli etc. also developed under Maratha rule.


Describing the lay-out of the new city of Shahjahanbad, Bernier says that the style of housing had to suit


the climate conditions of India, being airy was very important, as also having terraces to sleep in the


open at night during the hot weather. He says: "Very few of the houses are built entirely of brick or


stone, and several are made only of clay and straw, yet they are airy and pleasant, most of them having


courts and gardens being commodious inside and having good furniture. The thatched roof is supported


by a layer of long handsome and strong canes, and the clay walls are covered with a fine white lime".


Intermixed with these houses, and the shops above whom the merchants lived, were an immense


number of small ones, built of


367


mud and thatched with straw, in which lived the common soldiers, the vast multitude of servants and


camp followers.


It is wrong to think that all the streets were narrow, crooked and unpaved. In each town there were one


or two principal roads, which formed chowks. The roads were generally paved. The city was divided into


wards or mohallas in which people of one caste or profession generally lived, though we have mohallas


at Delhi consisting of both Hindus and Muslims. The mohalla was locked up at night for security - a


practice which seems to be returning to Delhi in recent times.


It has been argued that cities in India did not have a specific legal character of their own, like many


towns in Europe, and hence had no civic life. This judgement needs, however, to be modified. The


general administration of the city in India was in the hands of the kotwal who had his own staff for


watch and ward. In special cases, he could ask the faujdar for help. Apart from regulating weights and


measures, and keep track of prices, prohibit illegal cesses etc. he had a number of civic duties such as to


appoint persons to look after the water courses, prohibit the selling of slaves, set the idle to some


handicrafts and to organize people in reciprocal assistance in the mohallas, and appoint a guild-master


for every guild of artificers. We know that in many cities there were heads of traders (malik-ut-tujjar or


Nagar seths), sometimes on a caste or religious basis. Thus, there was a structure of local consultation


and participation. The kotwal was also to act as an intelligence agent, keeping track of the coming and


going of peoples, births and deaths, census operations etc.


In general, the point to note is that the administrative structure of towns was such as to discharge in a


satisfactory manner the effective purposes of town-life.


Artisans and Master-Craftsmen


The number of workers in constructing royal buildings in medieval India was enormous. We are told that


Alauddin Khalji engaged 70,000 workers for his buildings. Babur claimed that 680 workmen worked daily


on his buildings at Agra, while 1491 men worked as stone-cutters in his buildings at Agra, Sikri, Bayana,


Dholpur etc. Under Akbar, 3 - 4,000 artisans, labourers and other functionaries worked daily to


construct the Agra fort. In addition, 8,000 labourers were employed to supply stone and lime. If


Tavernier is to be believed, "twenty thousand men worked


368


incessantly" to construct the Taj Mahal. If to this we add the workers needed for constructing the


houses of the nobles, the artisans and labourers used in the building industry alone would be enormous.


In addition there were the artisans who were employed in the various manufactures, urban and rural. It


is impossible to form any idea of the number of these artisans except to say that though generally


organized on a caste basis, there was sufficient flexibility for the numbers in any craft being added to in


case of growth of demand. The major industry was, undoubtedly, the textile industry based on cotton


but supplemented by silk or tussar mainly produced in Bengal, and often used to make cloth mixed with


cotton and silk or painted. Carpentry which included ship-building, and production of leather goods


were other major industries, supplemented by metallurgy, paper making, glass making etc.


It has been remarked that the Indian craftsman was able to produce goods of very high quality with very


simple tools. One cause of this was general indifference to labour saving devices on account of a limited


domestic market, and fear of unemployment if such devices were introduced. Thus, in 1672, the Dutch


in Coromandal had successfully introduced a technique which quadrupled production of iron nails and


cannon balls. Local authorities banned the new technique lest it deprives many locksmiths of their


livelihood. Tapan Raychaudhuri notes, "Both early modern Europe and medieval China were fa r ahead of


mid-eighteenth century India in such crucial fields of technology as the use of wind and water power,


metallurgy, printing, nautical instruments, and basic tools and precision instruments."


This does not, of course, mean that no technological progress was made in Medival India. India was able


to produce, mainly at Surat, ships as good as any sent from Europe to Asia, as also manufacture heavy


guns. There also had been modifications in the technique of raw-silk reeling, indigo or saltpetre


manufacture and the arts of dyeing and printing cloth at the instance of European companies. This


showed that the Indian artisaus were not opposed to new technique as long as it did not threaten their


livelihood, and augmented their income.


Unlike Europe, the concentration of manufacuring industries in the towns to the exclusion of the villages


did not take place in India. The villages in India continued not only with traditional


369


crafts like manufacture of sugar, oil, indigo, raw silk, etc., but also developed localized centres of


production. Thus, in the coastal area from Madras to Armagaon, there were artisan villages which


specialized in producing cloth for export. According to Orme, in Bengal, near the main road and large


towns, by the middle of the 18th century, there was hardly a village where every inhabitant was not


engaged in the manufacture of textiles. Such examples can also be cited for other regions, such as


Gujarat, Awadh, etc.


In the main, the artisans still worked on a domestic basis. Thus, in a weaving family, women and children


cleaned the cotton, and spun the thread, men worked over the loom. In general, the artisans owned


their tools of trade. It was only in the royal karkhanas that the craftsmen worked at one place under


supervision, and were provided with the tools and raw materials. This may have been copied by a few of


the richer, powerful nobles. It was only in some enterprises, such as large construction of public


buildings and public works such as tanks, diamond mining, ship-building etc. that workers were brought


together, and worked under some kind of superior supervision. We are told that in all 20,000 or 30,000


workers were employed in the diamond mining field, with 2000-3000 workers employed by one


contractor. But in most cases, these were ad-hoc organizations, the workers dispersing as soon as the


work in hand had been completed. In other words, there was hardly any stable organization for large


scale enterprises.


Artisans may be classified broadly into two categories. On the one hand were the rural artisans who


were only part time artisans, and often indistinguishable from cultivators. These included oil-pressers,


indigo and saltpetre workers, sugar manufacturers etc. Their work was seasonal and many of them


worked in manufacture for only five or six months in a year. However, as demand increased, they


sometimes let out their lands for others to cultivate. The same applied to cocoon producers, as demand


for silk grew. Weavers were part of the traditional system of supplying cloth to the villagers in return for


a share of the produce. Often they had a small family plot of land to fall upon and to keep them tied


down to the village. They sold their surplus produce in the market.


The second category were the professional artisans in towns and villagers. As trade and manufacture


grew, the merchants


370


gradually extended their control over the professional artisans through the dadni or putting out system.


They not only brought the artisans under control not only by giving them loans, but providing raw


materials, and even laying down the size, patterns etc. of the piece. Thus, in the Coromandal, Kasi


Viranna had brought under his control all the weaver settlements between Madras and Armgaon so that


they were called "Virenna's villages". In such cases, despite owning their own looms, the artisans tended


to become wage earners because the cost of the raw materials and their labour was prescribed by the


trader. Thus, in 1676, local merchants in Madras told representatives of the English East India Company


that they "had raised the wages of their weavers to get a better quality of cloth". However, this was not


capitalist production in the real sense of the word. The Russian scholar, Chicherov, calls it


"deconcentrated capitalist manufacture". He says: "It does not, however, lead to the overthrow of the


old mode of production, but rather tends to preserve and retain it.... This system presents everywhere


an obstacle to the real capitalist mode of production".


An alternate path of development was the emergence of master craftsmen to the position of organisers


of production and merchants and financers. The growth of master-craftsmen, called ustads in Medieval


India, is a little studied subject. That this section had grown both economically and socially is indicated


by Abul Fazl placing these sections, whom he calls "artificiers", in the second rank in society, side by side


with merchants, below nobles and warriors, but above the learned and the religious classes. The social


importance of the master-craftsmen is indicated by two available farmans of Akbar granting lands to


two master-craftsmen. In Bengal, there were affluent master-weavers employing their own capital who


sold freely on their own accounts. In mid-eighteenth century, we hear of a master printer of textiles in


Awadh who had as many as 500 apprentices. In Kashmir, in the shawl industry, there were mastercraftsmen who owned upto 300 looms. There were master-carpenters at Surat, and in Bengal and Bihar


who hired carpenters for ad hoc work. Thus, as Tapan Raychaudhury observes. "The emergence of


artisans as 'capitalist-enterpreneurs'-Marx's 'truly revolutionary way' in the transition from merchantile


to indudstrial capitalism - was thus not absent from the Indian scene."


371


Women


Women have certain common problems, such as their dependence on father, husband or son, and the


effects of the male dominated patriarchal family system which operated all over India, except in some


areas such as Kerala and many tribal areas. Within these limits, the lives of the upper class women and


working women were very different. The upper class women were generally educated, and lived a life of


luxury, though confined to the inmates of the haram, and sharing the husband with numerous w ives and


mistresses. Some of these women played an active part in politics, as ruler themselves. Such as Rani


Durgawati of Gondwana and Chand Bibi of Ahmadnagar or exercising political power through their


husbands, like Nur Jahan. There were others such as Jahanara, daughter of Shah Jahan, who was closely


associated in the political processes, both under Shah Jahan, and under aurangzeb after the death of


Shah Jahan. Many other women, such as the vegetable seller Zuhra during the reign of Muhammad


Shah, or his queen, Udham Bai, a former dancing girl, played a role in politics during the period of


Mughal decline.


However, more important than this was the role of women in giving moral and cultural tone to society


from behind the curtains. They influenced royal taste and patronage, and themselves extended


patronage to artists, singers etc. Some of them have many literary works to their credit. Thus, Jahanara


wrote under the pen-name "Makhfi" (concealed). Roshanara set up a literary atalier (bait-ul-ulum) at


Delhi to which Aurangzeb had banished her.


Many harmful social practices, such as child marriage, or forced marriages, denial of a share in parental


property etc. also continued in medieval times. Akbar tried to fix the age of marriage for boys and girls,


give freedom to girls to marry on their own and not under parental pressure. But these were largely


disregarded. Likewise, there was little impact on Mughal attempt to regulate sati because all the


important Rajput rajas continued to practise it. Thus, when Maharaja Man Singh Kachhwaha died at


Elichpur in the Deccan in 1614, four ranis committed sati along with him, and another five at Amber. Of


course, that large numbers of ranis, whose names and pedigrees are given in contemporary Rajasthani


sources, lived on as widows after the death of a ruler suggests that there was no


372


over-whelming pressure on them to commit sati. However, an unfortunate practice was that in order to


increase the sacred honour that accrued to a ruler from the women who commited sati , the number of


such women was increased by making many common law wives and maids who had been called to the


bed of the ruler and given a special status, and who generally belonged to the non-Rajput sections and


the lower castes, were made to commit sati. Thus, when Maharaja Anup Singh of Bikaner died in 1698,


apart from 2 ranis, 9 common law wives (kkawas, patar, khalsa) and 7 maids (sahelis) committed sati.


Divorce was generally not favoured by the Muslim nobles, though we have a few instances of it.


Regarding property, after escheat, the ruler distributed the property of a deceased noble according to


his likes among the sons. There are no references to a share of the property being given to daughters of


nobles. But such laws may have been enforced by the courts for other Muslims.


For women belonging to the common fold, life was hard. We see in paintings women working in building


activities, along with infants. Working women received wages which were lower than those given to


men. Thus, in Kota, according to official figures, women working in the fields received lower wages than


men. Women specialized in some vocations. Thus, spinning was widely practised by women of almost all


classes. In Bengal the fine thread from which the famous muslin of Dacca was woven was prepared by


women, often belonging to upper castes, who had nimble fingers and a keen eye-sight. We are told that


such women received the wages of a skilled worker, that is, upto Rs.3 per month. The chikan work for


which Awadh was famous was also a speciality of women. However, it is clear that all such women


worked under the tight control of a merchant, or a master craftsman.


Servants and Slaves


European traders and travellers who came to India during the sixteenth centuries remark on the number


of servants and retainers the rulers and members of the ruling classes employed, both for ostentation


and show, and for service in their large households. Moreland who dwells upon it in his India at the


Death of Akbar, says "much of the domestic service rendered was sheer waste", and that its effect was


"to withdraw from useful


373


employment a large share of the energy and resources of the people, and to direct them towards


unprofitable expenditure".


It may be noted that the service sector formed a large section in all feudal socie ties. Apart from work in


the fields in the villages, and manual labour and manufacture in the cities, the only employment


opportunity at a slightly higher level (excluding the armed forces) was service with the king and


members of the feudal nobility. The limited nature of employment opportunities in such societies is


shown by the existence of large numbers of beggars in the cities. The large class of clerics, monks,


wandering religious ministrals etc. was another class to which Morland's remark could be applied.


It should not, however, be forgotten that service with the ruling class was an escape from rural drugery


for many, and their slightly higher living standards provided employment opportunities to the large class


of artisans. These sections also felt that they had a right to share in the ruling classes' prosperity,


howsoever it was earned. In other words, standards applicable to modern societies cannot be


uncritically applied to pre-modern societies.


However, Moreland is right in stating that functions assigned to free men and slaves in service were, to a


large extent, interchangable. Slavery was an old institution in India, but by far and large, slaves were not


used for productive purposes in fields or manufacture. Firuz Tughlaq perhaps, was the only one who


used slaves for manufacture. The use of slaves for war purposes largely ended in India with the rise of


the Afghans. Akbar did use them in the army, calling them 'chelas', but for service purposes only.


Unlike the Sultanat period, we do not have many references to the price of slaves. Pyrard puts the price


of a slave-girl at the equivalent of about 50 rupees at Goa. The Portuguese employed slaves on a large


scale. The Portuguese Arakanese and Maghs made slave-raids into East. Bengal, and set up slave


markets at Chitagong, Sandwip, Hughi and Pipli. Goa was a busy market for slaves. Many of these slaves


were also sold in South-East Asia. Shaista Khan put an end to these raids in the time of Aurangzeb.


Slaves were obtained from various sources. There was a continuous import of slaves from East Africa


though on a small scale. The pilgrim-ships to Jeddah also indulged in slave trade.


374


Ships returning from the Red Sea, both European and Indian, would generally carry fifty slaves bought in


Mocha or Jeddah. Indian slaves were either hereditary and or captured from wars, or in raids in villages


allegedly for rebillion or non-payment of government dues. Many people sold their children for food in


times of famines which were frequent. Akbar banned the practice of enslaving prisoners of war, and


converting them to Islam. He also allowed people to re-purchase the children they had sold, and to


reconvert them. How effective these measures were is doubtful.


Although slaves in India were generally not mistreated, and it was considered an act of morality to free


slaves, slavery was debasing, and lowerd the status of free working men.


Standard of Living


Indigenous sources and accounts of foreign travellers who visited India during the 16th and 17th


centuries present a picture of a small group in the ruling class living a life of great ostentation and


luxury, contrasting it with the miserable condition of the masses - the peasants, the artisans and other


labouring classes. The sharp contrast between the standard of living of the ruling classes and the


peasants and the labouring classes was, of course, not peculiar to India, but existed in a greater or lesser


degree in all "civilized" countries of the world, including Europe, during that period.


We have little information about standard of life in the villages where the large majority of the people


lived. As we have seen, the Indian village was highly segmented both socially and economically, and


there was considerable inequality in distribution of land, though there was plenty of cultivable waste


land (banjar) available which could be brought under the plough if capital, labour and organisation were


forthcoming.


The share of the produce paid by the different categories of peasants is not easy to compute. The


general Mughal formula was from one-third to half. However, the precise share depended on a number


of factors - nature of the soil, strength of the owner - cultivator, nature of the zamindar dominating the


area, custom etc. Caste also played a role. Thus, in some parts of Rajasthan and Orissa, upper castes -the Brahmans, the Kshatriyas or Rajputs paid land-revenue at a concessional rate — sometimes 25%


whereas the others paid 40%. Village officials, such as the


375


village chaudhris, muqaddams etc. were also sometimes assessed at a concessional rate. Such


concessions were extended under special circumstances, such as the resettlement of a deserted village,


to ordinary cultivators as well. But in their case, the concessions was a temporary measure, the landrevenue increasing till it reached the normal rate in the third or fifth year.


It would be unrealistic to postulate a uniform standard of living for all th e peasants and artisans in a


village. Nor was every village similar to another. Some of the bigger villages served as grain collecting


centres, or had a local market (mandi). A higher proportion of the richer section of the peasants


including grain-dealers (mahajans) and money-lenders must have lived in these villages which developed


into qasbas.


We have already noted the disparities in village society. In lean years or during famine, while the poor


were driven to starvation or migration to the towns, the rich and a section of the middle peasants found


it an opportunity to bring the poor peasants into debt, or to acquire their lands and agricultural


implements.


Babur had observed that in India "peasants and people of low standing go about naked". He then goes


on to describe the decency-clout worn by the men and the 'sari' worn by the women. This is followed by


Abul Fazl, who says that the common people "for the most part went naked wearing only a cloth (lungi)


about the loins". Ralph Fitch, who wrote under Akbar, says that "the people go naked save a little cloth


bound about their middle, (but)... In the winter, which is our May, the men wear quilted gowns of


cotton and quilted caps."


The overwhelming impression is thus of scantiness of clothing. Though climatic factors and social


traditions cannot be discounted, scantiness of clothing was an index of poverty since the upper classes


and the privileged sections could be distinuished by the type and the quality of the clothese they wore.


In those days although cotton production and weaving were widespread in the country, cloth was more


expensive to wheat than at present.


Regarding women's clothese, we have already referred to the sari which was generally made of cotton.


Moreland points out that women did not wear any blouses with their sari, and treats it as an illustration


of paucity of clothing. However, it may be pointed out that in many rural areas of eastern India, till


recent times, wearing of a blouse was not common. In Malabar, both


376


men and women, irrespective of their means, did not wear anything above their waists. In north western India, the blouse (choli or angiyd) was worn by ordinary women even in rural area. Thus, the


contemporary Hindi writer, Surdas, mentions the choli or angiya of various colours worn by the milkmaids of the Agra-Mathura region.


While the ordinary people wore no shoes, and went about with bare feet, wearing of shoes was


apparently considered a mark of respectability and was used by the richer section in the villages. The


shepards, masons, labourers and palki-bearers are depicted in contemporary paintings as wearing


shoes.


Then as now, women, both rich and poor, wore jewellery profusely which has been described by


contemporary writers, both in Persian and regional languages, in considerable detail. It is also depicted


by many painters of the period. Foreign travellers also dwell on this as a strange phenomenon. Ralph


Fitch, writing of Patna, said "Here the women be so bedecked with silver and copper that it is strange to


see, they use no shoes by reason of the rings of silver and copper they wear on their toes". In addition to


gold, silver and copper ornaments and those made in glass or ivory were used.


The housing of the poor in rural areas has not changed much since the Mughal times. The bulk of the


peasants lived in single room houses made of mud with thatched roofs. The houses of the working class


in the south were "nothing but huts covered with cajan leaves." They were so low that a person could


not stand upright in them. The rooms would not generally have any windows on account of the hot


climate, the entrance being sufficient for light and air. Manrique found that the houses were kept very


clean with frequent plastering of the ground and the walls with mud mixed with cow-dung. But in


Gujarat the houses were roofed with tiles (khaprail) and often built of brick and lime. Houses in Bengal


and Orissa were made of bomboo or reed with thatched roofs.


Utensils made of bell-metal or copper were expensive and were generally not used by the poor. The


only iron used was the "small iron hearths" used by the common people for baking their bread.


It is clear from contemporary accounts that the articles in the diet of the common people in India


consisted chiefly of rice, millets and pulses. In Bengal, Orissa, Sindh, Kashmir and parts


377


of South India, rice being the major crop was the staple diet of the masses. Millet (juwar and bajra) held


the same position in western India (Rajasthan and Gujarat). A modern writer, Irfan Habib, says that


"generally speaking, it was the lowest varietieis, out of his produce, which the peasant was able to retain


for his own family." Wheat was not apparently a part of the diet of the common people in the wheat


producing region of Agra-Delhi. Writing of Malwa, Terry says that "the ordinary sort of people" did not


eat wheat, but used the flour of "a coarser grain," made up in round broad and thick cakes (chapatis)"


which were "wholesome and hearty". Foodgrains were supplemented by herbs (saga), beans and other


vegetables which were produced in the villages and by fish in Bengal, Orissa and the coastal areas


including Sindh.


In the Delhi-Agra region, however, Palseart says of the workmen that "for their monotonous daily food


they have nothing but a little kitchery (khichri) made of the green pulse, mixed with rice... eaten with


butter in the evening, in the day time they munch a little parched pulse or other grain (sattu)".


Then as now, some money was spent on fairs and festivals which were frequent. They provided


welcome relief to the villagers in their drab lives and an opportunity to buy products not produced in the


village. Money was also spent on birth and death ceremonies and marriages, and sometimes debts had


to be contracted for the purpose. Famine and epidemics were two of the scourages, in the lives of the


villagers. Famines were of frequent occurance, the severe ones being often accompanied by epidemics


which depopulated villages. Nevertheless, for many writers of the time in regional languages, village life


was an ideal and both joys and sorrow had to be faced with equanimity.


We are on somewhat firmer ground in assessing the standard of living of the workmen since their wages


have been given in the Ain, and also by many travellers. According to the Ain, an ordinary labourer got


about 2 dams a day or Rs.11/2 per month while a superior labourer could hope to get 3 to 4 dams a day


or Rs.21/4 to 3 per month. Carpenters got 3 to 7 dams and builders from 5 to 7 dams per day. Pietro


Delia Vella says that at Surat servants cost very little - Rs.3 a month. It has been computed that the basic


necessities of a person could be met by Rs.1 a month while Rs.2 a month was sufficient to feed a family


of five. Slaves were numerous and lived on nothing except their keep. Pelsaert


378


says that palanquin - bearers (porters) got Rs.4 a month for short journeys, but Rs.5 a month for


journeys of more than sixty days. Soldiers hired for protection got the same.


It is difficult to draw a comparison between the food available to the poor in medieval and modern


times. The peasant of Mughal times was more fortunate with ghee, while his modern descendant has


more salt and three entirely new articles of food, maize, potatoes and chillies. A modern Indian


economist, Ashok Desai, is of the opinion that in view of the larger average size of holding, higher


productivity of land and a more favourable land-man ratio, "The standards of food consumption were


substantially higher than now".


By comparing prices and wages between Akbar's time and the present, we may conclude that while a


wage-earner could have purchased more wheat than a modern worker, it was an item which hardly


figures in his diet. On the other hand, he could purchase more gram, barley, milk and ghee, as also goatmeat as compared to a modern workman. But few of the workmen (excluding Muslims) ate meat.


According to Ashok Desai, "the purchasing power of the wages was nearly the same in 1595 and 1961.


But the low paid worker of Akbar's time was able to keep the standard of nutrition much higher than


now because of cheap meat, ghee and milk. Sugar and gur were expensive; even salt a little costlier for


him".


The upper classes in India consisted of nobles, the autonomous rajas and chiefs, and the wealthy


merchants in towns. Their living standards have been discussed when dealing with them.


The Ruling Classes


The ruling classes in Medieval India may be broadly divided into two - the nobility which represented


royal power or central authority, and the class of local rulers or chiefs and landed elites or zamindars


who represented local power. However, no hard and fast distinction can be made between the two


because from the time of the Lodis, and increasingly from the time of Akbar, local chiefs and landed


elements began to be incorporated into the nobility and associated even more closely than before into


the local administrative system. Relations between the two sections were often marked by tension and


strife. Simultaneously, mutual cooperation was needed and was sought for local purposes, including the


task of expanding and improving cultivation while


379


the local rulers often sought legitimization from the centre. A common feature, between the two was


that both depended and drew their financial resources from the surplus labour of the peasant who


cultivated the land. Thus, in this context both were basically feudal in nature.


The Nobility


Unlike Europe, the nobility in India was not a legal category but indicated a class of people who were not


only involved in the tasks of government at the higher level but reflected a certain level of culture and


urbanity. Both the numbers and composition of the nobility underwent a change as the Mughal empire


was consolidated, and expanded to cover the entire country. Thus, between 1595 and 1656-57, while


the numbers of the high mansabdars remained more or less fixed at 25, the medium mansabdars


(500/1000 to 2500) more than doubled from 98 to 225. The composition of the nobility also changed.


The nobles who came to India at the time of Babur and Humayun, or came to India during the reign of


Akbar were mainly drawn from the homeland of the Mughals — Turan, and Khurasan, along with Uzbeks


and Tajiks. As we have seen, the Mughals never followed a narrow racialist policy. From the time of


Akbar, Shaikhzadas or Indian Muslims, and Rajputs representing the indigenous ruling class also began


to be inducted into the nobility. Babur tried to induct many of the leading Afghans into the nobility, but


the Afghans proved restless and untrustworthy. Heightened struggle with the Afghans under Humanyun,


and with Akbar in Bihar, Bengal and Orissa led to the virtual exclusion of the Afghans from higher posts


in the nobility. But the process began to be reversed under Jahangir, Khan-i-Jahan Lodi being a favourite.


In the time of Aurangzeb, many Afghans from the Deccan states entered the Mughal nobility.


The Iranis and Turanis, for whom the word Mughal was used, continued to be the largest group in the


nobility, forming as much as 40 per cent of the nobles holding ranks of 1000 zat and above even during


the last 25 years of Aurangzeb's reign, between 1679 and 1707. However, less than a quarter of these,


i.e. less than 10 per cent of the total nobles holding a mansab of 1000 zat and, above had been born


outside India. Thus, Bernier's statement that the Mughal nobles were "foreigners who enticed each


other to the court" hardly holds up to a critical scrutiny.


380


Bernier's statement that the immigrants "are generally persons of low descent, some having been


originally slaves, and the majority being destitute of education" is even more off the mark. The Mughals


gave special favours to those of high descent, while a good literary education was considered vital for


future progress. It should also be kept in mind that the immigrants came to India with their families, and


made India their home. They also assimilated themselves into the prevailing Indo-Mughal court culture.


Thus, they were no longer foreigners in any real sense of the term. However, this did not mean that


social distinctions between the Iranis, Turanis and the Indians disappeared. Those, who could trace a


foreign ancestry considered themselves to be a privileged and superior group, and tended to marry


among themselves.


Although the position of the nobles was not hereditary, those whose ancestors had been in the service


of the king for more than a generation were called khanazads, or the house born ones. They felt a


special affinity with the ruling house, and claimed a privileged position in the grant of mansabs. Thus, in


the period between 1679 - 1707, the proportion of Khanazads i.e. descendants of mansabdars, excluding


sons-in-law, among those holding ranks of 1000 zat and above, was almost half. Even this did not satisfy


the old mansabdars since there was a lot of pending demand for mansabs among their wards. Despite


its limitations, the Mughal nobility was not a closed shop, but fairly open in its recrui tment policy. At the


same time, the Mughal nobility was highly hierarchical in nature, with the senior positions being virtually


reserved for the nobly born, including the Hindu rajas. Thus, in the period 1658 - 79, the number of


Iranis and Turani nobles holding ranks of 5000 and above was over 60 per cent while the leading Rajput


rajas formed another 11 per cent. Even then, there was a chance for people with an ordinary


background reaching the highest posts, as in the case of Rai Patr Das .under Akbar, and Rai Raghunath


under Shah Jahan and Aurangzeb.


The top heavy nature of the Mughal nobility is shown in other ways as well. Thus, it has been calculated


that in Shah Jahan's reign, 73 members of the upper elite received 33,091 crore dams or 37.6 per cent of


the entire assessed income of the empire. The personal salaries they enjoyed put them on par with


autonomous rajas of a middle size kingdom. By all accounts, the life style of the high nobles was very


opulent. They had large multi-storied


381


mansions with gardens and running water, a large haram and a multitude of male and female retainers


and servants. A single house in the Deccan fit for a noble cost Rs.1,50,000. Rich carpets, costly curtains


and richly decorated inlay furniture consisting of bedsteads, mirrors, chairs and stools were considered


necessary. The roof was richly gilded, and the floor and the walls covered with fine plaster. A lot of


money was spent on the table. We are told that a hundred dishes used to be prepared for Abul Fazl


every day. A lot was spent on fruits, and imported wines. Ice which was an item of luxury was used all


the year round. Apart from China ware which was a luxury, gold and silver vessels were used widely.


Another costly item was the stables. Every noble had to maintain a sizeable number of beasts of burden


- elephants, camels, mules, and horses, as well as carts, palanquins etc. for transport. Tents were


another costly item of equipment


Both men and women were accustomed to use jewels for adorning different parts of their body. From


the time of Jahangir, men pierced their ears for putting pearls. Costly clothes, generally of cotton, plain


or painted, and silk, plain or stripped, brocades and costly shawls made in Kashmir were also used


widely.


It was also considered necessary for a leading noble to extend patronage to the arts. Thus, poets,


musicians, painters etc. sometimes received extravagent rewards. Abdur Rahim Khan-i-Khana, son of


Bairam Khan, was reputed to give ass-loads of money to every poet who composed a panegyric in his


name. The extravagent gifts of many nobles to their retainers, and grants of lands and gifts to holy men


are also mentioned.


Thus, as Moreland stated, "spending not hoarding" was the dominant characteristic of the pattern of life


of the nobles. This was a common feature of the landed gentry the world over. However, prudent nobles


could save money. Contemporary chronicles give us the names of many nobles who left large sums of


money and valuables at their death. Thus, when Ali Mardan Khan died in 1657, Shah Jahan escheated his


property, amounting in cash and goods to one crore of rupees. Azam Khan Koka (4000/4000) governor


of Bengal, left 22 lakhs of rupees and 1,12,000 muhars. Muhammad Amin Khan, subedar of Gujarat who


died in 1682, left seventy lakhs of rupees and one lakh seventyfive thousand ashrafis and large number


of animals including ten chests of Chinaware of all kinds which were


382


escheated by Aurangzeb. The purpose of escheat basically was to recover from the nobles the money


most nobles took as advance from the state. After this had been done, the balance was distributed by


the monarch among the heirs of the noble according to his estimate of their worth. The sharai laws in


this matter were disregarded, because the Mughal rulers claimed to be the owners of all the property of


their nobles. Aurangzeb modified this rule in 1666. The property of only those nobles was escheated


who had dues towards the state. But the rulers reserved to themselves the right to distribute the


property left behind by the nobles according to his likes and dislikes.


Two aspects of the nobility need to be noted. As the empire was consolidated, the nobles began to be


subjected to even more detailed rules and regulations regarding their salaries and promotion, conduct


of business, rewards, even deportment. These were set out in regulations called dastur-ul-amal.


Normally, a mansabdar started with a small mansab and was promoted according to rules and


regulations (zabta) though the ruler could always depart from them. Thus, an element of bureaucracy


was introduced in the functioning of the nobility. The manner in which meticulous records were


maintained from the village level upwards re-inforced this.


Second, the Mughal nobles, including the monarchs and members of the royal family, were not allergic


to trade. Some of them supplemented their income by trade, and by investing their money with traders.


Abul Fazl advised the nobles "to indulge a little in commercial speculation and engage in remunerative


undertakings, reserving a portion in goods and wares, and somewhat invested in the speculation of


others." Disregarding the Islamic injunction on taking of interest, Abul Fazl exhorts the nobles that "a


share may be entrusted to borrowers of credit." He ends by saying, "Let such a one be frank in his


commercial dealings, and give no place in his heart to self-reproach."


It is difficult to estimate the extent of the commercial dealings of the Mughal nobles. It has been pointed


out that during the seventeenth century, members of the royal family, including kings, princes,


princesses and ladies of the haram engaged in commercial ventures. Thus, Jahangir, Nur Jahan, Prince


Khurram, and the Queen Mother owned ships which plied between Surat and the Red Sea ports. This


was continued under Shah Jahan and even under Aurangzeb.


383


Many nobles carried on trade in their own name, or in partnership with merchants. Thus, Mir Jumla had


a fleet of ships which sailed to Burma, Macassar and Maldives, Persia, Arabia etc. Other prominent


nobles, such as Asaf Khan, Safi Khan etc. also owned ships. The English factor at Surat wrote in 1614,


"great and small are merchants." Some nobles tried to misuse their official positions for profit. Thus, as


governor of Lahore, Wazir Khan got a commission on everything that was bought and sold at Lahore. As


Governor of Bengal, Mir Jumla and later Shaista Khan tried to monopolise trade in all important


commodities. Thus, Shaista Khan extended from time to time his monopoly over saltpere, bees wax and


even fodder. Prince Azim-ush-Shan tried to force merchants to uy at prices dictated by him in the name


of sauda-i-khas, but had to modify it after a sharp reproof from Aurangzeb. However, even the chief


Qazi of Aurangzeb, Qazi Abdul Wahab, had substantial commercial undertakings which be tried to


conceal from Aurangzeb.


It would appear that as trade and commerce expanded following the Mughal peace, and growth of


foreign trade to which the foreign companies contributed, the Mughal nobility, members of the royal


family, and even judicial and ecclesiasted officials become more commerce minded. A modern author,


Tapan Raychandhuri, considers the involvement of these elements in commerce to be of "dubious


value". Although the trade by the nobles was only a fraction of the total trade in the country, it did imply


diverting a part of the resources siphoned off from agriculture into domestic and foreign trade. The


nobles also gave patronage to skilled manufactures, and the trade they created. Tavernier says, "on


arrival for embarking at Surat, you find plenty of money. For it is the principal trade of the nobles of


India to place their money on vessels on speculation for Hormuz, Basra and Mocha, and even for


Bantam, Achin and Philippines." Thus, even Mir Jumla lent money to the English.


The greed of the nobles for money led to a good deal of corruption. No action would be carried out


without giving or receiving presents. Nobles at the court who had access to the Emperor, sometimes


sold their good offices to the highest bidder. Thus, Qabil Khan, the mir munshi of Aurangzeb, amassed


12 lakhs in cash and valuables during his two and a half years of service. It was for this reason that the


Mughal nobles, and clerks in the administration, had earned a bad reputation for bribery


384


and corruption. However, the nobles also built mosques, hospices, sarais, covered markets (katara),


khanqahs and dug water-tanks in the places where they settled down. They also bought land to build


orchards. Not all of these were for profit, but were considered meritorious acts. Thus, the upkeep of


mosques, sarais, hospices, etc. was sometimes met from the income of the markets and orchards.


The urge of the nobles for money made them more grasping in their dealings with the peasants.


According to Shaikh Farid Bhakhari, who wrote a biography of Mughal nobles in the early years of Shah


Jahan's reign, Jahangir's mir bakhshi and favourite, Farid Bukhari, expected fifty percent more revenue


from the amils from his jagir, and if for that reason the peasants migrated, he would surrender that jagir


and obtain another in its place. How general this was is difficult to say. Imperial policy laid great


emphasisa on the expansion and improvement of cultivation and there was a machinery for checking


the oppression of the jagirdars. Official policy and private approaches did not always match.


The French traveller, Bernier, tells us how the peasantry, on account of the demands of the rapacious


lords, were driven to despair at "so excecrable a tyranny" and had to flee to the neighbouring Rajas.


Bernier traces this to absence of private property in land on the part of the nobles, or the jagir system of


transferability. He argued that the "Timariots" or jagirdars had no interest in the improvement of land


because of its transferability. We do have some instances of nobles who founded villages. But neither


the French landed gentry whom Bernier defends nor the Rajput nobility as a class appear to have taken


much interest in the improvement of cultivation. Bernier's argument that the jagir system was inimical


to expansion and improvement of cultivation is not borne out by the evidence at our disposal.


Rural Gentry or Zamindars


There was a great deal of discussion during the early part of British rule regarding the nature and


position of the zamindars, and whether they were owners of the land or merely collectors of landrevenue. Recent research has shown that the word zamindar which began to be used from the 14th


century, and came in general use during the 17th century, covered a wide range of


385


rights and privileges in different parts of the country. Etymologically, a person who owned the land or


zamin he cultivated was a zaminidar. The word is still used in this sense in some parts of the country


such as Punjab. But in Mughal parlence, the word was used to designate one who was the owner (malik)


of the lands of a village or township (qasba), and also carries on cultivation. According to a modern


author, Irfan Habib, zamindari was therefore, "a right which belonged to a rural class other than, and


standing above, the peasantry." This is the sense in which the word zamindar was generallay


understood, although the Mughals sometimes used the word for autonomous rajas and chiefs also in


order to emphasise their dependent status. While autonomous rajas paid a fixed sum in money and


goods as peshkash, and were left free to assess and collect land revenue from the peasants in their area


of control, the attempt of the state was to fix the land revenue directly with the peasants in the areas


under central control. Thus, there was a constant effort to convert autonomous chiefs into kharaj


collecting zamindars on the part of the state, and for the zamindars to shake off all imperial control.


The zamindars formed the apex of rural life. They had their own armed forces, and generally lived in


forts or garhis which was both a place of refuge and a status symbol. The combined forces of the


zamindars were considerable. According to the Ain, in Akbar's reign they had 3,84,558 sawars, 42,77,057


foot-soldiers, 1,863 elephants, and 4,260 cannons. But the zamindars were dispersed and could never


field such large forces at any time or at one place. The figures perhaps also include the forces of the


subordinate rajas.


The zamindars generally had close connections on a caste, clan or tribal basis with the peasants settled


in their zamindaris. They had considerable local information also about the productivity of land. The


zamindars formed a very numerous and powerful class which was to be found all over the country under


different names such as deshmukh, patil, nayak, etc. Thus, it was not easy for any central authority to


ignore or alienate them.


It is difficult to say anything about the living standards of the zamindars. Compared to the nobles, their


income was limited. The smaller ones may have lived more or less like affluent peasants. However, the


living standards of the larger zamindars might have approached those of petty rajas or nobles. Most of


386


the zamindars apparently lived in the countryside and formed a kind of a loose, dispersed local gentry.


The zamindari right was both hereditary and saleable, and from the time of Akbar there are many


examples of zamindari being sold in whole or part. There was no restriction on caste or religion in the


sales, though in Maharashtra we have documents of the village community or patil agreeing to the sale.


Zamindari could also be divided like any property.


The zamindari right implied both financial income and social prestige. The actual income of a zamindar


from his zamindari was generally sought to be concealed, and local officials were always asked to


ascertain and control it. Generally, the zamindars had the right to a share of the produce which was paid


in cash and kind. Thus, in Awadh, the zamindari right implied a claim to take 10 sers of the crop for eac h


bigha and one copper coin (dam) from the same area. The zamindar could also levy other cesses, such as


impost on forest and water produce, tax on marriages and births, house-tax etc. The charges of the


zamindars varied from area to area, being called biswi (1/20), or do-biswi (1/ 10), or satarhi (1/17), or


chauthai (1/4). The attempt of the Mughal government was to fix the dues of the zamindars and


consolidate them in the land revenue. In such cases, the dues of the zamindars were assessed at 10 per


cent and called malikana. Malikana could be paid either in cash, or by grant of revenue-free land called


nankar. But it would have been difficult to prevent the zamindars from making illegal exactions from the


peasants including forced labour (begar) for transportation etc.


Sometimes, zamindars were allowed to collect land revenue from a tract beyond their own zamindari.


This was generallay called a talluqa. For this area, the zamindar was only a tax-collector, and was paid


remuneration by way of nankar or revenue-free land.


The attempt of the Mughal government to convert the zamindars who were traditionally considered the


enemies of a strong central government into agents of the government in the rural areas was a step


which had far reaching implications, but also one which bristled with difficulties. The zamindars had


caste / clan or historical associations with the peasants, and had considerable knowledge about land and


its productivity. The government wanted to utilize this knowledge to maximize their land revenue


collections. Simultaneously, it tried to squeeze the


387


zamindars by establishing direct contact with the cultivators, especially the owner-cultivators, or the


malik-i-zamin. Since the zamindars were themselves an exploiting class, the state, to some extent, set


limit on their extortions. But where the zamindars joined with the cultivators to resist the rapacity of the


state, a position of confrontation was created.


It would not be correct to look upon the zamindars merely as those who fought for control over


land,and exploited the cultivators in the area they dominated. Many of the zamindars had close caste


and kinship ties with the land-owning cultivating castes in their zamindari. These zamindars not only set


social standard, but also provided capital and organisation for settling new villages, or extending and


improving cultivation. However, success in this field depended in large measure upon the help and


cooperation of the khud-kasht cultivators who dominated the village community, owned the physical


resources, and could provide manpower.


While the zamindars formed a numerous and powerful class, not all the villages were under the control


of zamindars. Thus, the revenue records of the period divided villages, even within a pargana, into


raiyati or non-zamindari and talluqa i.e. zamindari. In collecting the land-revenue from their talluqa, the


zamindars had to follow the government rules. Nor could they expel a peasant from his land. In fact, in a


situation where land was surplus, the zamindars had every reason for the cultivators to stay, and to


cultivate as much land as possible. The peasants were not serfs, and were free to stay or to leave


according to their wish, but local officials were asked to use every effort, including where necessary


force, to prevent them from leaving.


The Middle Strata


There has been a lot of discussion whether during the medieval period, India had a middle class or not.


The Frenchman, Bernier, said that in India there was no "middle state", a person was either extremely


rich, or lived miserably. It is, however, not possible to agree with this statement. The word "middle


class" means traders and shop keepers. India had a large class of rich traders and merchants, some of


them being amongst the richest merchants of the world at that time. These merchants also had their


own rights based on tradition, and right of protection of life and property. But they did not have the


right to administer any


388


of the towns. Such rights had been acquired in Europe by the merchants in special circumstances. Also,


these rights tended to be abridged whenever strong territorial states grow up, as in France and Britain.


If by middle class, however, we mean a class of people who did not receive a share in feudal property,


but were paid for their professional services, we find a large class of professional and service groups in


the towns which may be considered a part of the urban intelligentsia. The Mughal administrative system


was such that it needed an army of accountants and clerks, for the state, as also for nobles and even


merchants. Rich artisans could also live much above the standards of the poor.


Contemporary evidence suggests that certain categories of revenue officials formed a very prosperous


group. Thus, amils and karkuns supplemented their income by defalcating land revenue through false


account books, and by corruption and brikery. Since many of them were drawn from the khatri and


bania castes, or were Jains, they undertook side business, such as cultivation, usury, speculation in


commodities, horticulture, revenue farming, management of rent yielding properties in the towns etc.


We have instances of karoris (treasurers) depositing cash collected by them with mahajans for long


periods on interest. These sections were rich enough to buy good houses in towns. Some of them even


led a life rivalling that of a high noble. In Aurangzeb's time, Abdus Samad Khan, atnin and faujdar of


Jahanabad, established a small town in the name of his son. The property included orchards, a sarai, and


Turkish hamams.


An idea of the wealth accumulated by these sections is provided by the fact that in 1725, the political


authorities at Ahmadabad were able to extort Rs.5,73,000/- from eight officials residing there. In


general, revenue officials had a poor reputation, and had on occasions to suffer prison and other


indignities to make them disgorge their ill -gotton gains.


Among the professionals, medical practitioners (tabib) catered not only to nobles, but to wide sections,


including petty officials, merchants and traders, smaller mansabdars and urban professionals and rich


artisans. While some of the tabibs were attached to rulers and high nobles, and received mansabs, many


of them conducted private practice. Thus, the Italian, Manucci, tells us that when his service with Dara


in the artillery department ended, he set up a


389


private practice at Lahore, and that he soon earned a name so that people came from places distant


from Lahore to visit him as patients.


Musicians, calligraphists and teachers also belonged to the section of professionals. Writers, historians,


and theologians were often drawn from the same urban middle class intelligentsia though sometimes


they received a rent-free land, thus bringing them nearer to the feudal classes.


Thus, the 'middle strata' had different interests and was drawn from various religious and caste groups.


The Commercial Classes


The commercial classes in India were large in numbers, widely spread out and highly professional. Some


specialised in long distance inter-regional trade, and some in local, retail trade. The former were called


seth, bohra or modi, while the latter were called beoparis or banik. In addition to retailing goods, the


baniks had their own agents in the villages and townships, with whose help they purchased foodgrains


and cash-crops. The words bania (baniya) or baqqal (foodgrain merchant) were sometimes used for


them. The bania also acted as a money-lender in rural areas, and hence generally had a poor reputation


for being grasping and extortionate. However, they did discharge a positive role in the economy by


enabling food-grains to be transported from villages and mandis to towns, and to different regions in


the country, and providing rural capital.


The trading community in India did not belong to one caste or religion. The Gujarati merchants included


Hindus, Jains and Muslims who were mostly Bohras. In Rajasthan, Oswals/ Maheshwaris and Agrawals


began to be called Marwaris. Overland trade to Central Asia was in the hands of Multanis, Afghans and


Khatris. Traders in Bengal were called gandha-banik, though these seem to have been largely displaced


later by Afghan and Muslim traders. The Marwaris spread out to Maharashtra and Bengal during the


18th century. The Chettiyars on the Coromandal coast and the Muslim merchants of Malabar, both


Indian (Chuliyas, Mapillahas) and Arab, formed the most important trading communities of South India.


The trading community in India, especially in the port towns, included some of the richest merchants


who are comparable in wealth and power to the merchant princes of Europe. The Portuguese merchant,


Godinho, stated in 1663 that the Surat


390


merchants were "very rich", some of them worth more than 50 or 60 lakhs of rupees. They had fifty


ships trading with various overseas countries. Virji Vohra who dominated the Surat trade for several


decades owned a large fleet of ships. He was reputed to be one of the wealthiest men of his time. He


bought opium and cotton from local merchants exchanged these for pepper in Malabar and South east


Asia, and supplied them to English and Dutch traders. His capital at one time was reputed to be 80 lakhs


of rupees. Other Gujarati merchants, who could each buy up an entire ship's cargo or supply the entire


annual investment of the European companies are repeatedly mentioned in the sources. Abdul Ghafur


Bohra left 85 lakhs rupees in cash and goods, and a fleet of 17 sea-going ships at the time of his death in


1718. Similarly, Malay Chetti of the Coromandal coast, Kashi Viranna and Sunca Rama Chetti were


reputed to be extremely wealthy, and had extensive commercial dealings in India and abroad. There


were many wealthy merchants at Agra, Delhi, Balasore (Qrissa), and Bengal also. Some of these


merchants, especially those living in the coastal towns, lived in an ostentatious manner, and aped the


manner of the nobles.


Regarding the living style of the merchants, there seemed to have been a considerable variation, based


on circumstances. Bernier says that the merchants tried to look poor because they were afraid of being


used like "fill' sponges", i.e. squeezed of their wealth. Nobles did sometimes abuse their position,


specially during times of uncertainty, as happened at Jaunpur at the time of Akbar's death. According to


the Jain merchant. Banarsidas, Princes sometimes extorted forced loans. But, on the whole, such cases


appear to be the exception rather than the rule. Thus, the author of the book Mirat-i-Ahmadi, dealing


with Gujarat, tells us that there were two suburbs of Ahmadabad which he call its "two golden wings".


These were inhabited by wealthy Hindus who were "millionaire bankers."


European travellers mention the commodious and well-built houses in which the wealthy merchants of


Agra and Delhi lived. The ordinary sorts lived in houses above their shops. But even these, according to


Bernier, were "tolerably commodious within". In Delhi, some of the houses of merchants were double


storeyed and had beautiful terraced roofs. Nor did all of them try to conceal their riches. We are told


that at Agra, one Sabal Singh Sahu, was so "intoxicated with prosperity" that his court


391


"resembled that of princes". However, social practices and traditions must also be kept in mind.


Tavernier speaks of the "extreme parsimony of shroffs and of all Indians in general," and describes how


the baniyas "accustom their children at an early age to shun slothfulness" and to learn the arts of


acquiring wealth.


While merchants had to be prepared for some official harassment, the properties of the merchants,


were generally not in danger. The law of escheat applied to the nobles did not affect them. Emperors


from the time of Sher Shah passed many laws for protecting the property of the merchants. Jahangir's


ordinances included a provision that, "if anyone, whether unbeliever or Musalman should die, his


property and effects should be left for his heirs, and no one should interfere with them".


Despite complaints by some European travellers, safety on the road was generally satisfactory.


Banarsidas who frequently travelled between Agra, Jaipur and Patna during the latter years of Akbar and


under Jahangir, was robbed only once. Goods were also insured, and the low rates of insurance - from


1/2 to 1 percent from Surat or Ahmedabad to Thatta, Masulipatnam or Daman (but going upto 2 1/2%)


shows that the risk was not considered high.


Means of transport were cheap and adequate for their needs. The means of travel with sarais at the


distance of 5 kos on the principal highways was as good as in Europe at the time. Nevertheless, trade


and the traders continued to have a low social status. The influence of the merchants on political


processes is a matter of controversy. Merchants in India were not without influence in political quarters


where their own interests were concerned. Thus, each community of merchants had its leader or


nagarseth who could intercede with the local officials on their behalf. We do have instances of strikes


(hartal) by merchants in Ahmadabad and elsewhere to stress their points of view and to protest against


official harassment. At Bhaganagar (Hyderabad) when the French traveller, Thevenot, was there, Hindu


bankers shut up their offices in protest against an Amir's exactions until the ruler ordered restitution of


the seized property. Traders are also known to have gone on hartal in protest against levying of jizyah. In





1668-69, the Surat baniyas went on strike against the forced conversion of a person to Islam.

No comments:

Post a Comment